Journal Browser
Open Access Journal Article

Housing Prices and Land Use Regulations: A Study of 250 Major US Cities

by Theo S. Eicher a,* orcid
a
Department of Economics, University of Washington, Seattle, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Received: 7 June 2023 / Accepted: 2 July 2023 / Published Online: 2 March 2024

Abstract

Income and population growth are key determinants of housing demand, while land use regulations are designed to affect housing supply. Previous studies of housing price determinants focus either on specific regulations in particular cities/regions, or on selective subsets of major cities and regulations. This study examines the impact of land use regulations on housing prices from 1989 to 2006 in an unusually large sample of 250 major US cities. Aside from factors that are commonly associated with housing demand (income, population growth and density), housing prices are found to be associated with local cost-increasing land use regulations (approval delays) and with statewide regulations. Since statewide regulations factor prominently into the results, specific examples of the impact of different types of land use regulations are provided for 5 cities in the state of Washington. The estimated increase in housing prices associated with regulations is, on average (over 250 cities), substantially larger than the effects of income and population growth. While the estimated dollar costs associated with regulations may be sizable at times, the results are remarkably consistent with previous studies that were based on smaller cross sections.


Copyright: © 2024 by Eicher. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY) (Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) or licensor are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

1. Introduction

Housing prices follow the fundamental laws of supply and demand. The challenge for economists is to identify the specific factors that are associated with housing supply and demand. Economic theory is clear: changes in housing prices are associated primarily with income and demographic factors on the demand side, and with costs considerations (e.g., land use regulations) on the supply side.[1] Price, income, and demographic data are readily available from government sources, but it has proven to be extraordinarily costly and time consuming to obtain objective and comparative land use regulation data for informative, representative studies.
In surveying the housing literature, one is struck by the abundance of studies that focus on the effects of specific regulations in particular cities. Authors surveying the literature at times succumb to the temptation of generalizing results from the numerous city/region-specific studies, in hopes of establishing broad patterns that link regulations to housing prices (see, for example Nelson et al. 2004).[2] Although studies of individual jurisdictions may be informative, it is unclear whether it is possible to generalize their findings. For example, the economic impact of zoning restrictions that affect lot sizes in California are distinctly different from building height restrictions in New York. Individual city studies may also be susceptible to “selection bias” by which researchers’ site selection and data collection may systematically influence results to validate prior expectations. Even cross-city studies that examine several dozen major metropolitan areas may be subject to selection bias. Glaeser and Gyourko (2002) point out, for example, that smaller datasets which feature only large metropolitan areas may oversample highly regulated cities and underrepresent the bulk of American housing that featured robust growth and available land.
This paper examines 250 major US cities documents to identify the effects of land use regulations on housing prices. This regulatory dataset was produced by an extensive land use study at the Wharton Business School for the University of Pennsylvania. Researchers at Wharton’s Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center executed a nationwide survey of residential land use regulations in over 2,700 US communities (Gyourko et al., 2008). Aside from legal variables, the Wharton database is therefore not based on researchers’ or consultants’ assessments but it represents data collected from each city’s planning director that is now made available to researchers. The dataset provides a first opportunity to examine the specific regulations that can be associated with changes in housing prices across a large number of US cities. The broad cross section approach eliminates nagging doubts whether a particular result for a particular city is also relevant to other regions.
Often-cited reasons for the escalation of US housing prices in the past 10-20 years include lower mortgage rates, creative mortgages, and income/employment growth. These factors, which may well contribute to increasing housing prices, all relate exclusively to housing demand. Housing supply factors, however, are harder to quantify and are typified by opposing view points: for example, environment vs. sprawl, builders vs. planners, parks vs. high-rises, and state vs. local growth management. Growth management often refers to: 1) urban growth boundaries, 2) regulation of development densities (e.g., minimum lot-size rules), and 3) cost-increasing regulations (facility development and/or regulatory delays in the approval process).
The Wharton database provides objective and comparative information on 70 land use regulations that cover growth boundaries, density and cost-increasing regulations. This paper reports how this data can be used in regression analysis to identify the effects of land use regulations on housing prices. The results are highly statistically significant and indicate a substantial association between regulations and changes in housing prices. Aside from demand factors, four regulations are shown to be robustly related to changes in real housing prices across the 250 cities between 1989 and 2006: 1) permit delays, 2) statewide land use regulations, 3) court support for statewide regulations, and 4) growth management.
Since these regulations speak to both local and state wide regulations, it is useful to provide an example of the effects of regulations on different cities within one state. Such an example can highlight that the costs of regulations can differ even within a particular state (Washington State) among cities that are subject to similar statewide regulations. The variations in the costs of regulation are then due to substantially different local regulation and demand environments, as well as the degrees to which municipalities are affected by the statewide regulations. While the magnitudes reported may seem surprisingly large, Section 6.1 shows that these findings are remarkably consistent with results from a number of previous studies based on smaller cross sections of cities.
Combining the 2730 cities in the Wharton Sample with 2006 Census data renders a sample of 250 major US cities. The focus on the link between regulatory restrictions and housing prices is controversial in the planning literature. As Glaeser (2004) points out, housing demand factors have long been considered central determinants of housing prices. In the early 1980s, Poterba (1984) and Summers (1981) documented that inflation increased the interest rate subsidy on mortgages to such an extent that the resulting shift in housing demand explained much of the run up in housing prices in the 1970s. Mankiw and Weil (1991) highlighted that demographics also drive housing demand. Given the aging of the US population, their results yielded the ominous prediction that “real housing prices will fall substantially over the next two decades.” Contrary to the Mankiw and Weil forecast, housing prices across 250 major US cities rose 54 percent (after accounting for inflation) from 1989-2006.[3]
Housing supply determinants have only recently come under intense scrutiny. Seminal was the special issue of the Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics devoted to housing supply (Rosenthal, 1999), which contains several surveys that cover distinct dimensions of housing supply. Subsequently, Green et al. (2005) estimate a detailed housing supply function for 45 major cities. This line of research has culminated in a voluminous literature that documents a robust association between housing prices and the stringency of land use regulations. Glaeser (2004) summarizes the evidence and provides broad and compelling support from studies of US regions and cities (see also Appendix 3).
Finally, it is also important to highlight that the economic analysis below provides cost estimates of regulations, but it cannot identify whether such regulations are socially optimal. For the same reason it cannot provide value judgments that identify regulations as “good,” “bad,” or “misguided.” Think about it this way: citizens may well value regulations even more than the price they have to pay for them! Nelson et al. (2004) make this point forcefully when they point out that growth restrictions in Boulder, Colorado, drove up the price of housing near green belts, and that this price increase reflected nothing other than the willingness to pay (in the sense that wealthier citizens simply revealed their preference for pretty views).
What is often neglected, however, is that these very examples also highlight that regulations and affordable housing have been mutually exclusive (see, e.g., Seattle Times, 2008). In the absence of normative guidance, it falls to the electorate to decide whether the benefits derived exceed the associated costs in terms of housing price increases. Alternatively, the cost estimates here provide guidance that can assist policy reviews/updates. As Nelson et al. (2004) point out, “if housing prices may increase in any land use environment, then the decision is between good and bad regulation to improve housing choice.” Brueckner (2007) reminds us that growth management policy interventions “are often well-meaning, being designed to achieve ends that are thought to be socially desirable.” The problem is that the complexity of the urban real estate markets may create subsidiary effects that are either unanticipated or unforeseen by policy makers and planners alike. To assure against adverse effects, policy review must be frequent to reoptimize when unintended effects compromise the designed effects of regulations.

2. Previous Comparative Studies of Housing Prices and Regulations

2.1. Comparative Studies of US Metropolitan Areas
A large number of studies exist that examine the effects of specific demand and supply factors on housing prices in particular cities. As discussed in the introduction, it is difficult to derive general implications from such studies. Instead, the results below are based on a large cross section. Before these results are presented, however, it is important to review the methods and findings from previous cross sectional studies of housing prices and regulations. This review focuses only on relationships between housing prices and regulations. Other papers, not cited below, focus on the impact of regulations on permits, construction, and land availability.
Black and Hoben (1985) first developed a measure of “restrictive”, “normal”, or “permissive” regulations for 30 US metropolitan areas. They report a correlation of –0.7 between their regulation index and 1980 prices for developable lots. Segal and Srinivasan (1985) surveyed planning officials in 51 metropolitan areas to find the percentage of undeveloped land taken out of production due to land use regulations. They estimated that regulated cities have 1.7 percent faster annual housing price increases than unregulated cities. With compounding, this actually turns out to generate a dramatic impact on housing prices over a decade (about 20 percent). As an alternative, Guidry et al. (1991) employed land use and environmental data from the American Institute of Planners (AIP, 1976) to find that land prices in cities with more stringent land use controls increased 16 percent for every 10 percent increase in their regulatory measure. Guidry et al. (1991) also examined regulation data from the Urban Land Institute[4] to find that average lot prices in the most restrictive cities in 1990 were about $26,000 higher, than in the least regulated cities.
One of the most prominent comparative studies is Malpezzi (1996) who examines 56 US metropolitan areas. He built his analysis on regulatory data collected by the Wharton Urban Decentralization Project carried out by Linneman et al. (1990).[5] Despite its comparatively large coverage, Malpezzi’s data lacks information on key metropolitan areas (such as Seattle). He focuses squarely on cost-increasing regulations (zoning and permit time costs) and adds a variable to indicate when states regulate environmental impacts (coastal, wetland or floodplain management). His findings imply that moving from lightly regulated to highly regulated cities reduces housing permits by 42 percent and increases housing prices by 51 percent. Malpezzi et al. (1998) use a hedonic price index and show that regulations increased housing prices by 31-46 percent. Phillips and Goodstein examined 37 metropolitan areas and found that the Malpezzi (1996) regulatory index was associated with higher housing prices, although a proxy for the effect of the urban growth boundary in Portland was shown to be less than $10,000 per unit. Downs (2002) increased the sample of metropolitan areas to 86 and examines the period of 1990 to 2000. He does not find an effect of regulations on housing prices for all periods, only for 1990-2000, 1990-94 and 1990-96.
Glaeser and Gyourko (2002) examine lot prices in 40 US cities, controlling for the change in the cost of construction. They label the gap between the actual housing prices and the cost of construction (minus the lot price) provocatively the “zoning tax.” Table 1 is a reproduction of their results showing the change in housing prices relative to construction costs in major cities and suburbs. They associate their zoning taxes with cost-increasing regulations (time to permit issuance for zoning requests) and find a statistically significant relationship.
2.2. Comparative Regional Studies
Other large scale studies are regional, such as Katz and Rosen's (1987), who analyzed 85 cities in the San Francisco Bay area to find that housing prices increased between 17-38 percent in communities with growth control measures. Levine (1999) expanded Katz and Rosen’s approach to 490 Californian cities and 18 different land use measures. He finds that land use restrictions “displaced new construction, particularly rental housing, possibly exacerbating the expansion of the metropolitan areas into the interiors of the state.” Pollakowski and Wachter (1990) examined 17 zoning jurisdictions in Montgomery County, Maryland, over a period of eight years and found that a 10 percent increase in these zoning restrictions increased housing prices by 27 percent. Interestingly, they also provided evidence on the externalities associated with regulations: housing prices are shown to rise when the restrictiveness of zoning measures in adjacent jurisdictions increased.
Downs (1992) examined the effects of growth management plans in San Diego County, CA, to find a housing shortage in the five largest cities was aggravated by growth controls that increased prices of existing homes by 54 percent and prices of new homes by 61 percent in three years. Cho and Linneman (1993) examine 10 districts in Virginia and found that zoning restrictions had a significant impact on housing price within the district and via spillovers to nearby jurisdictions. Green (1999) examined zoning and permitting regulations in 39 municipalities in Wisconsin and found that two of the regulatory variables had modest impacts on price increases. Finally, Gyourko and Summers (2006) analyze 218 jurisdictions around Philadelphia and find that areas with average land use regulations saw slightly negative increases in the real cost of single family lots over 10 years. The most restrictive municipalities, in contrast, saw lot cost increases of up to 70 percent (for a summary see Appendix 3). Finally Glaeser et al. (2006a, b) report on a study of 187 communities in eastern Massachusetts to find that regulation, not density, has caused low levels of new construction and high housing prices in the Greater Boston area. The reduction in permits caused by the regulations has had a significant effect on regional housing prices, which were increased median housing prices by 23-36 percent or about $156,000.
The sample of cities featured in this paper is roughly identical in size to the samples in Gyourko and Sommers (2006), and Glaeser et al. (2006a, b); instead of covering only one region, however, the sample below is comprised of 250 major US cities. It shares with previous comparative studies that zoning restrictions and approval delays are considered, but it also extends the focus of previous analyses to include statewide measures, such as growth management plans and even court rulings regarding regulatory enforcement. Malpezzi (1996) also considers statewide measures, but the structure of his data assumes that the effect of such regulations is identical across cities. Instead, the Wharton database provides information on the degree to which each city is impacted by statewide regulations. Finally, instead of focusing on only one or a couple of regulations, it is also examined whether a given individual regulation in the Wharton database potentially affects housing prices.

3. Supply and Demand for Housing

Before moving to the formal statistical analysis, it is important to review the basic mechanics of housing supply and demand. The following section closely follows the lucid framework laid out by Malpezzi (1996); it can also be found in any introductory urban/real estate economics textbook (e.g., O’Sullivan, 2003). Figure 1 represents a simple housing market for identical units. In a free market, supply and demand curves (S1 and D1, respectively) intersect at the equilibrium point, A. Point A maximizes private welfare as it equates the private costs to the private benefits for housing units.
In the presence of an externality[6], however, society faces a potential market failure. In the context of real estate economics, an example of such an externality would be the public’s desire for parks and green spaces. Such desires raise the social cost of supplying housing above the private cost to shift the supply curve up to S2. From society’s perspective, the equilibrium at point A now represents “too much” housing at “too low” a price and policies that regulate housing to coincide with point B would deliver the socially preferred outcome. The difference between the housing quantities and prices at A and B is then the social cost of attaining the public benefit of reduced housing. This cost includes a welfare loss that each citizen incurs due to the reduction in housing units and the associated increase in prices.
Note that there also exist housing externalities that increase social benefits beyond private benefits. Such externalities lower the social cost of housing supply.[7] In this case, the welfare maximizing policy interventions are regulations that expand housing and lower its price (take, for example, affordable housing requirements). The housing framework therefore highlights two important insights: 1) there is no reason to expect housing prices to rise, due to regulations that are intended to attain the social optimum, 2) a rise in housing prices due to regulations indicates that policy-makers associate a negative externality with the supply of housing. Finally, note that the cost increases associated with regulations must match the associated social valuation. To understand whether cost increases and social valuations match requires a clear understanding of the cost and benefits of regulations. It is easier to support regulations when the associated costs are not identified.
The supply and demand relationships are approximated by a model that provides the foundation to the empirical approach outlined in Section 4. Readers less interested in the exact mechanics of the model can skip to Section 4.3. The interim sections employ economics and statistics jargon to provide the necessary methodological foundations. The housing model presented below is largely identical to Malpezzi (1996). More complex models of housing prices can certainly be constructed; their empirical implementation is, however, often associated with insurmountable obstacles.[8] The below analysis is therefore a compromise that acknowledges the tradeoff between model complexity and data availability.
The standard model of the median owner-occupied house depends on the demand and supply of owner occupied housing, Q h o D and Q h o S , respectively. Demand is a function of the relative price of the median owner occupied home, P h o , median income, I h o , and demographic variables, D , that relate to density and population size. The demand relationship can then be formally represented as
QhoD=FDPho,Iho,D
(1)
The supply of the median owner occupied housing, QhoS, is assumed to depend on the relative price of the median owner occupied home, Pho, land use regulations, R, and the prices of all i inputs, PiS (e.g., construction costs)
QhoS=FSPho,R,PiS
(2)
Construction costs are largely set at the national level and are also considered in the methodology as described below. Aside from construction costs, other input prices (such as land) may themselves be contaminated by regulations. In this case, Malpezzi suggests to rewrite (2) by substituting for PiS to represent the supply side equation as the following reduced form
QhoS=FSPho,R
(2')
The reduced form in equation (2’) has received additional validity from Green et al. (2005), who estimate detailed, theory-based housing supply equations and find that regulations and low supply elasticities are strongly positively correlated with heavily regulations in metropolitan areas. The specification in (2’) highlights that regulatory changes affect housing prices both directly and indirectly. The direct effect of regulations is a reduction in the supply of housing and an increase in the price of housing. An indirect effect of regulations is a change in input prices, which would then affect the supply of housing. The statistical analysis below captures the net impact of both the direct and indirect effects.
In equilibrium, supply and demand are equalized, allowing us to solve equations (1) and (2’) simultaneously for the housing price. This renders housing prices a function of land use regulations, income, and demographic variables
Pho=FR,Iho,D,ε
(3)
To translate the structural model into a statistical regression model, a stochastic term, ε, is added in (3). Evidence for omitted variables or measurement error is captured in the error term. To examine the validity of the proposed empirical model, the properties of this error term are examined extensively in the robustness analysis reported in Appendix 1.

4. Econometric Implementation of the Housing Model

4.1. The Empirical Model
The reduced form in (3) is commonly estimated “in levels,” which indicates that the variable of interest, Pho, is the price level. In terms of the econometrics, the standard cross-section estimator (be it ordinary least squares, or any variant that allows for non-spherical disturbances) is only consistent when individual city characteristics (so called “fixed effects”) can be assumed to be uncorrelated with the variable of interest. It is doubtful whether this assumption is valid in the context of housing prices. City fixed effects, such as the designation as state capital, proximity to Disney World, or to nature, may well drive the level of housing prices. One approach to address fixed effects is to estimate (3) in terms of growth rates, so that the omitted variable bias associated with city-specific fixed effects is mitigated. While “nature” and “geographical characteristics” may influence cities’ price levels, it is a much taller order to link them to changes in prices.
The second issue is that level regressions are generally thought to be susceptible to spurious correlations in the absence of true causal relationships. Causality is certainly not guaranteed in growth regressions, they do mitigate spurious correlation. This renders growth regressions a much more stringent empirical test. Third, in contrast to level regressions, growth regressions can address the frequent confusion in the public debate about the short and long term drivers of housing. The demand for housing – as seen above – is determined by variables that can change quite quickly over time (income, migration, and density). Housing supply instead is by its very nature much more inelastic, especially in the short run (it takes months to purchase land, obtain permits, construct a home, and sell it). Examining the change in housing prices over long time periods (17 years, in the sample below) allows the regressions to capture the effects of both supply and demand measures with some confidence.[9]
Most importantly, however, growth regressions speak effectively to the question at hand: which variables can be associated with the change in housing prices across major US cities? Or: did housing prices increase because of land use restrictions and/or income/population growth? Level regressions, instead, speak only to the question of whether housing prices are high in cities with high incomes, large populations, and extensive regulations. The estimates below are therefore based on growth regressions where the variable of interest is the annual compounded growth rate of housing prices from 1989-2006. This renders the regression to be estimated
P^ho=α+β1R+β2I^ho+β3Pop^+β4Density+ε
(4)
where variables with “^” subscripts represent growth rates, Pop is the population and Density is the population density of a particular city (see Appendix 2).[10] The constant, α, is included to account for effects that are common to all cities over this period of time. Such effects might represent changes in the national level of unemployment, changes in mortgage rates or lending procedures, or liquidity in the mortgage market.[11]
4.2. Housing Price Data
Much of the housing literature wrestles not only with the development of meaningful land use regulation data; even the measurement of its key variable, housing prices, is subject to controversy. There are three alternative approaches to housing prices: i) median housing prices for owner occupied homes as reported by the Census, ii) sales price data collected by the National Association of Realtors, and iii) so-called “hedonic” price indices that take into account the characteristics of the housing unit. All three measures are used in the literature as each measure features distinctly different advantages.
It has been suggested that the correlation among these three housing price measures is so high that one should not expect the choice of the type of price data to drive qualitative results (Malpezzi, 1996). Prices given by i) and ii) suffer the drawback that they do not control for quality increases (such as larger homes, smaller lots, nicer appliances, etc.). While Census data has the broadest coverage, it reports only median owner occupied housing prices. The National Association of Realtor data features a broader breadth of data, since it is based on multiple listings. However, multiple listing data does not capture the entire market, so ii) also does not constitute a representative sample.
In theory, hedonic price indices adjust housing prices for housing quality. This method requires the use of a “hedonic regression” to obtain the estimates of the contribution of each housing characteristic (e.g., an extra bathroom) to the price of a home. These estimates are then used to artificially construct an imputed quality-adjusted housing price. This quality-adjusted price construct is as reliable and error prone as the hedonic regression itself. If the true regression model is not known, the estimated housing price is subject to measurement and omitted variable errors that bias the contributions of all characteristics to the imputed, quality-adjusted price. Housing price studies seldom report the actual hedonic regressions that are the basis for the quality-adjusted housing prices used; if the information is provided, it highlights at times the problematic nature of the procedure.
For example, in a study of housing prices in eight Washington State counties, Crellin et al. (2006) account for quality by controlling for a) assessed value, b) lot size, c) dwelling size, and d) number of bathrooms. Their hedonic regressions imply that the number of bathrooms either has no influence on housing prices or a counterintuitive effect (e.g., more bathrooms imply lower housing prices) for some counties. Malpezzi et al. (1998) also report their hedonic regressions, using a much larger sample than Crellin et al. (2006) by examining 373 US locations with a median sample size of 3000 home owners each (some samples exceed 70,000 owners). Their hedonic regressions control for 19 different housing quality characteristics; but at least one quarter of their mean regression coefficients exhibit counterintuitive effects, and many are estimated with such large standard errors that few characteristics can be expected to be statistically significant (e.g., to affect the housing price). Problematic properties of hedonic regressions then contaminate the imputed quality adjusted housing price. Heravi and Silver (2002) have also questioned the usefulness of the hedonic approach on theoretical grounds, by highlighting how sensitive such regressions are to the small changes in methodologies.[12]
The 2006 Census data does not provide sufficient information to attempt hedonic regressions, which simplifies the choice of housing data. To cover the largest possible sample and to avoid oversampling highly regulated cities, the only option is to follow the examples in scholarly journals set by Malpezzi (1996), Thorson (1996), Malpezzi et al. (1998), Green (1999), Phillips and Goldstein (2000), and Malpezzi (2002) to employ housing price data from the US Census Bureau. Two additional sources of pricing data are at times mentioned in the public press (though never in large cross sectional studies). One is the Standard & Poor's/Case-Shiller Home Price Index, the other is the Shelter Component of the Consumer Price Index (CPI) produced by the US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
The S&P/Case-Shiller data controls best for housing quality as it tracks repeat sales of specific single family homes. Going back to 1990, the index features, however, only 15 metropolitan areas and excludes new construction. The exclusion of new construction is especially relevant to the analysis here, since new construction represents the balance between housing supply and demand in unrestricted markets. The cost of not using the quality adjusted S&P index turns out to be small. The index produces similar growth rates of housing prices as the US Census data used below. For example, for Seattle, LA, NY, San Francisco, Denver, Boston, Portland and San Diego, the difference between the nominal annual growth (1989/90-2006) in housing prices for the Standard & Poor's/Case-Shiller metropolitan areas and the Census cities is less than 1 percent.[13]
The Shelter Component of the CPI is both controversial and problematic. It experienced nine major revisions since its inception in 1950 and two fundamental revisions over the period of analysis in this paper. The Shelter Component tracks only consumption-related housing costs while regulations affect the asset price of a home. Housing consumption costs are essentially proxied by the apartment rental prices and an implicit “rental equivalence” that had been imputed for owner occupied housing. Since the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ 1997 revision of the shelter component, it is widely acknowledged that the measure has “lost what little connection it had recognized between the rental and owner-occupied markets” (Carson, 2006). This disconnect is reflected in the sharp rise in housing prices in the early 2000s (as tracked by the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ own data), which was associated with a sharp drop in home owners’ “rental equivalence” (perhaps due to the lower cost of funds or factors specific to the rental market).
4.3. Housing Demand Data
Census data for the 2730 jurisdictions in the Wharton database are available only from the decennial Census. To provide a timely analysis, the 2006 Census Bureau’s Public-Use Microdata Sample (PUMS) is used here, which covers a sample of major US cities with a minimum of 10,000 inhabitants. The intersection between the 2730 jurisdictions in the Wharton Database and the 2006 PUMS Census data renders a universe of about 250 cities (depending on the exact variable). The Census is also the source of the population data that was used to calculate population and land area (to obtain city density). Finally, the Census also provided data on median household income. Summary statistics are provided in Appendix 2.
4.4. Land Use Regulation Data
As mentioned in the introduction, the land use literature is now fortunate enough to find at its disposal a full dataset of 70 land use indicators. The Wharton Regulatory Database speaks to all three major components of land use regulations: urban growth boundaries, regulation of development densities, and cost-increasing regulations. A list of the data collected in the Wharton database is provided in Table 2. Many of these variables are highly correlated; therefore Gyourko et al. (2008) suggest the construction of a “Wharton Index” (formally the Wharton Residential Land Use Regulation Index).
The Wharton Index itself is composed of 11 sub-indices that reflect i) Local Political Pressure, ii) State Political Involvement Index, iii) State Court Involvement Index, iv) Local Zoning Approval Index, v) Local Project Approval Index, vi) Local Assembly Index, vii) Density Restrictions Index, viii) Open Space Index, ix) Exactions Index, x) Supply Restrictions Index, and xi) Approval Delay Index. The exact definitions of these indices are documented in
Gyourko et al. (2008). One key sub-index is the Approval Delay Index, which will be of consequence below. It is defined as the average time lag (in months) for three types of projects: i) relatively small, single-family projects involving fewer than 50 units; ii) larger single-family developments with more than 50 units, and iii) multifamily projects of indeterminate size. Table 3 ranks the 50 states by their regulatory stringency (Washington State is the 7th most regulated state) and Table 4 provides the rankings for metropolitan areas (the Seattle metropolitan is ranked 5th most regulated in the nation).
Gyourko et al. (2008) report average regulatory statistics by state and by metropolitan area. While it is common to use major metropolitan areas as the unit of analysis in cross sectional studies, actual city limits are used in the regressions below, since some important metropolitan areas are missing data for crucial cities that constitute substantial segments of the metropolitan region (for example, the Seattle metropolitan is lacking information on Bellevue). Most importantly, however, the land use data was collected at the city level; hence a city-level analysis best reflects the relationship between the observed prices and regulations. While the Wharton Index is informative as a broad measure of regulations, it is also of interest to conduct a deeper analysis that identifies which of the Wharton Index’ subcomponents may be related to changes in housing price. Examining each specific subcomponent’s explanatory power results in a clearly defined and readily interpretable set of variables associated with changes in housing prices.

5. Estimates of Supply and Demand Effects on Housing Prices

Figures 2a-d report simple correlations between the annual compounded growth in housing prices and the Wharton Index (Figure 2a), income growth (Figure 2b), population growth (Figure 2c), and population density (Figure 4d). The Figures exhibit clear, positive correlations, but also indicate that housing prices are not explained by any one variable alone. Multivariate regression analysis must be employed to capture all effects on housing prices. A regression that features only the influences of demand factors (income growth, population growth and density) on housing prices is provided in column 1 of Table 5. In total, demand factors explain about 20 percent of the variation in the housing price data (as indicated by the adjusted R2), and all three demand factors are highly significant.
The next regression adds the supply side to the regression and allows the Wharton Index to proxy for regulatory measures that influence supply. The results in column 2 of Table 5 indicate that the proportion of the variation in housing prices that is explained by the regression jumps over 20 percent when the Wharton Index is included. The root mean square errors indicate that the statistical model improves when the regression accounts for the association between land use regulations and housing prices. Thus there is clear evidence that land use regulations are tightly associated with the growth of housing prices in the broad cross section of 250 major US cities. This should not be surprising given a visual inspection of Figure 2a.
It is also crucial to note that the coefficients for the demand side regressors (income, population, and density) hardly change as land use regulations are added to the regression model (from Table 5 column 1 to column 2). This is a crucial insight, since it implies that land use regulations explain a different dimension of the variation in housing prices (e.g., the supply side). The invariance of the demand side coefficient estimates to the inclusion of land use regulation indicates also that the supply factors do not explain variation in housing prices at the expense of demand side measures. Instead, supply factors complement the insights derived from the effects of demand side measures on housing prices. Complementary here means that the inclusion of regulatory measures improves the statistical model and its predictive power without detracting from the importance of the demand side effects in explaining housing prices.
Since the coefficient associated with the Wharton Index in column 2 of Table 5 is positive and highly statistically significant; this indicates that more stringent land use regulations are associated with an increase in housing prices.
The low value for the Wharton Index in the dataset is -2.12, and the maximum is 4.65. The coefficient associated with the Wharton Index in column 2 of Table 5 then implies that housing prices in the most highly regulated cities are about 50 percent higher than those in the least regulated cities.[14] Interestingly, this implied increase in housing prices between lowest and highest regulated cities is just about identical to the finding in Malpezzi (1996), who based his study on 56 (vs. 250) cities, different regulation measures, and a regression in levels.
The analysis can be taken one step further to identify exactly which subcomponent(s) of the Wharton Index is (are) closely related to the change in housing prices. The advantage of constructing indices is that they summarize a wealth of information into one single figure; the disadvantage is that, for policy purposes, an index is difficult to interpret. The Wharton Index combines a wealth of information from 70 different types of land use regulations and it seems natural to ask whether specific regulations are particularly closely associated with changes in housing prices? Are prices driven, for example, by state or local policies, citizen opposition or growth management regulations, cost-increasing permit delays or limits on lot size?
To achieve this level of detail, the Wharton Index can be disaggregated into its subindices which can then be further dissected into their respective subcomponents (see Gyourko et al., 2008). A simple stepwise regression algorithm can then be used to examine one subcomponent after another to see whether the subindex holds explanatory power, and whether a subcomponent of a subindex holds explanatory power. If any of the subcomponents are significant, they are maintained in the regression; if not they are discarded. In the case of the approval delay subindex, the eight variables that constitute the index are highly sensitive to the inclusion of other subcomponents. Their explanatory power may be impacted by multicollinearity (e.g., cities with long permit delays for multi family projects with less than 50 units may also have long permit delays for multi family projects with more than 50 units). Therefore the approval delay index is maintained as a whole.
The final result of the disaggregation exercise is reported in column 3 in Table 5, which shows that a remarkably concise but diverse set of regulations can be shown to exhibit both economic and statistically significant association with housing prices. The regression model in column 3 in Table 5 explains 61 percent more variation in housing prices than the pure demand side regression in column 1 of Table 5. The disaggregated regression in column 3 also explains about 35 percent more variation in housing prices than the regression model that is based on the composite Wharton Index alone (Table 2b). Decomposing the Wharton Index to allow the individual dimensions of land use regulation to covary with housing prices thus clearly improved the regression model.
The specific regulatory variables from the Wharton database that have been substituted for the aggregate Wharton Index in regression 3 consist of statewide indicators, specifically indicators that speak to the executive, legislative and judicial branches of government. In addition, the types of regulations that are associated with changes in housing prices also speak to local regulations, cost-increasing regulations that involve permit and zoning delays: I) the constant terms picks up autonomous change in housing prices that are common to all cities, such as changes in the national unemployment rate, changes in mortgage interest rates or changes in the availability of credit over the period. II) Increase in Income and Population, III) Population Density, IV) Land Use Regulations imposed by IVa) the State Executive/Legislature. These statewide regulations are defined as the effects on major cities due to the level of activity in the executive and legislative branches over the past ten years, which were directed toward enacting greater statewide land use regulations. In addition, Land use Regulations cover IVb) Municipal Land Use Restrictions Upheld by Courts, which are defined as the effects on major cities due to the tendency of appellate courts to uphold or restrain land use regulation as well as IVc) Regulations Involving Growth Management and IVd) Permit Approval Delays.[15]
The statistical significance of each land use regressor is strong; all but Approval Delays are significant at the 99.99 percent confidence level (Approval Delays are significant at the 90 percent level).[16] The quality of these statistical results is discussed extensively in Appendix 1, which examines the residuals of the regression, which are defined as the difference between the actual housing price data and the predicted prices generated by the regression model. The appendix highlights two important features. First, there is no evidence that a key variable has been omitted from the statistical model in column 3. Second, the predictions of the model do not feature a systematic error across the 250 cities that might violate the statistical assumptions underlying the regression analysis. This provides evidence that the prediction errors of the regression model are random (e.g., accidental and not systematic).

6. The Cost of Regulations

6.1. Costs Implied by the 250 City Study
The association between regulations and housing prices can be expressed in terms of actual dollar costs. One approach is to compare housing prices associated with the highest/ lowest levels of land use restrictions (as in Section 5). This approach is standard in the literature and easily executed when only one regulation is considered. The above model consists, however, of four different dimensions of regulations, so there is no clear “lowest” and “highest” level of land use restriction. In this case, it is most informative to report the actual estimated dollar value that each regulation adds to housing prices. San Francisco is the city with the greatest direct dollar cost of regulations. After adjusting for inflation, all regulatory measures combined are estimated to have contributed $409,332 to San Francisco’s housing price between 1989 and 2006 (or 51 percent of the 2006 price). Since several regulations are state wide regulations, it is instructive to show, using 5 cities in the same state (Washington State) as an example, the cost of each regulation in each city.[17]
Table 6 indicates that, for example, in Seattle, the price of the median owner occupied home was $137,000 in 1989. In 2006, the US Census reports this price to be $448,000. The total price increase in Seattle from 1989 to 2006 was therefore $311,000. It is important to keep in mind, however, that the general price level increased from 1989 to 2006. Adjusting the data for inflation, housing prices in Seattle increased about $227,000, which represents the real (102 percent) increase in housing prices above and beyond the rise in the general price level. This is the price increase examined in the analysis above. Real price increases in the other cities in Table 6 are also substantially above the national average, which is 54 percent in this sample.
Demand factors (income and population growth) contributed $35,000 to the increase in real housing prices in Seattle from 1989-2006. This demand effect is significantly greater than the national average ($4,000) over the same period. This result is not surprising, since Seattle experienced above-average income and population growth over the past two decades. In Tacoma and Everett, income and population growth were lower than in Seattle and therefore demand factors are associated with smaller price increases in these areas. Kent and Vancouver, on the other hand, saw substantial increases in housing demand, perhaps due to their proximity to Seattle and Portland, respectively. Specifically, Vancouver’s increase in housing demand drove 40 percent of its real housing price increase ($54,000).[18] This indicates that even within a Washington State, variations in the demand are clearly reflected in the housing prices.
For all five Washington cities, the largest share of housing price increases was associated with regulations, which added about $203,000 to housing prices in Seattle. In Kent and Everett the regulatory environments are associated with $125,000 to $113,000 increases in housing prices, respectively. Statewide regulatory measures seem to have been particularly important in affecting Seattle’s housing prices, and the local approval delays contributed about $30,000. None of the four other cities ranked as high as Seattle in terms of approval delays. In fact in Tacoma the permit and rezoning effect is estimated to be just about negligible. By far the greatest impact is generated by statewide restrictions imposed by the level of activity in the executive and legislative branches over the past ten years in Washington State, while growth management contributed about $10,000 in Vancouver and $50,000 in Seattle.
6.2. Costs of Regulations Implied by Previous Studies
These estimated costs of regulations may seem extraordinarily large, but they are surprisingly close to previous estimates in studies that use smaller samples. Glaeser and Gyourko (2002) examine the effects of zoning on land values in forty major US cities. Their results circulated widely in the popular press after the Atlantic Monthly (Postrel, 2007) reported the study’s implied price increases due to regulations in major cities. For Seattle, Glaeser and Gyourko (2002) report a $201,000 price increase due to regulations.[19] Not all of the price increases in Glaeser and Gyourko (2002) coincide identically with the results predicted by the regression in column 3 of Table 5, but the overall correlation is an astonishing 0.91.[20]
A thorough review of the previous literature on housing prices and regulations highlights that not all studies report statistically significant results. This could be due to methodological problems, or regulatory indicators being combined into a single index, insufficient objective and comparable regulatory data, or the absence of an effect.[21] Comparative studies that do find statistical significant associations between regulations and housing prices are nevertheless numerous, and always document that regulations are associated with higher housing prices. As the survey in Table A.3.1 in Appendix 3 indicates, there are about two dozen studies in the past decades that show significant increases due to regulatory/growth controls – many suggest similar dollar costs as shown in the results above and in the Glaeser Gyourko study.
Mark Twain is at times credited with having coined the term “there are three types of lies: lies, damn lies, and statistics." The reported association between regulations and housing prices may simply seem implausible to some. Skeptics best turn their attention to the primary data to conduct the ultimate reality check: were regulations in cities where the regressions report high costs of regulations truly unusually restrictive? For example, was Washington State/Seattle truly as different from the average city as their dollar cost of regulations suggests? The regulation data in appendix 2, which as we recall was reported to Wharton by the cities’ planning directors themselves (!), indicates that Seattle is actually one of the most restrictive cities in terms of land use regulations in the entire sample. Table 3 had already shown that Washington State ranked 7th in the nation in terms of overall regulatory stringency. The appendix splits the rankings in Table 4 and Table 3 into the Wharton Index subcomponents that are relevant for these cities. Here it becomes apparent that the city of Seattle (not the Seattle metropolitan area reported in Table 4), ranks in the 98th percentile for the overall Wharton Index. That is, only 2 percent of the cities in the sample reported to Wharton that they have more restrictive residential land use regulations.
This overall Wharton Index ranking evaluates the stringency of a large number of individual land use regulations. Seattle ranks in the 90 percentile or higher in more than 16 key indicators. Several of the indicators (shaded) are related to approval delays. Other variables in the table are key regressors in the statistical model (the state court effect, the growth management effect and the legislative involvement index). Note that Kent especially is ranked almost as restrictive as Seattle; while Everett’s regulatory stringency places it in the 71st percentile. Vancouver is the counter example; its regulatory structure is about average (the 51st percentile), which explains why so much of its increase in housing prices was driven by demand.

7. What are the Effects of Statewide Regulations?

Why are the effects of statewide regulations associated with such strong increases in housing prices in these 5 major cities in Washington State? The answer lies in examining the land use restrictions of all Washington cities in the Wharton sample. Appendix 2 clearly reports that each city is affected differently by statewide land use measures. The most prominent statewide land use measure in the state is Washington’s Growth Management Act (GMA), enacted by the Washington Legislature in 1990. In 1995, the State Legislature added a requirement to review and update policies and regulations by 2004 on the basis of “Best Available Science.”[22]
Statewide growth management affects all jurisdictions identically in terms of the letter of the law.[23] However, to adhere to the letter of the law, individual jurisdictions may have to pass their own land use regulations to accommodate the growth targets. If statewide land use restrictions limit sprawl to create distinct low density peripheries and high density urban cores, each city is affected differently, depending on its individual supply and demand for housing. This is shown in the large variation of the Stateleg variable in Appendix 2. The effects of limits on growth are greater in metropolitan areas whose agglomeration pressures are stronger (see Duranton and Puga, 2004 for a review of agglomeration pressures). Statewide regulations limit growth in the periphery and redirect demand (and price pressures) to the metropolitan core. In the absence of such land use restrictions, cities such as New York or Las Vegas have been documented to easily accommodate great population growth (housing demand) without price pressures (see Glaeser, Gyourko and Sachs, 2005) presumably through increases in building heights and/or sprawl.
Statewide regulations may act as catalysts of agglomeration, but courts may also play a crucial role in complementing statewide growth management plans. For example, some argue that under Washington’s growth management plan, King County had few options but to require landowners in Seattle’s rural periphery to keep 50 to 65 percent of their property in its "natural state" (see Langston, 2004). This forced greater density in the urban core and it is difficult to see why such supply restrictions would not be accompanied by price responses.
It was important, however, that a challenge to the constitutionality of King County’s land use regulations was rejected by the Washington State Supreme court. The court clearly stated that state law required local governments to provide land use restrictions of the type imposed in King County in order to adhere to the statewide growth management plan. The state’s Supreme Court therefore rejected the validity of a King County referendum to repeal local regulations that were put into place explicitly to adhere to the statewide growth management plan (Ervin 2006). Charles Johnson, the Associate Chief Justice of the Supreme Court of the State of Washington, summarized the majority opinion succinctly: "where the state law requires local government to perform specific acts, those local actions are not subject to local referendum." If the dissenting justices had been in the majority, the teeth may well have been taken out of the implementation of the growth management plan in King County. This would have stopped the imposition of local regulations, and therefore mitigated the upward pressure on housing prices.
Note the importance of the interaction between state legislature and courts: state law forced local land use regulations, and the state court upheld local land use regulations because they were mandated by state law. The Seattle metropolitan area responded to the GMA mandate by instituting a Growth Management Planning Council (GMPC). A search of the council’s agendas and communications with the managers of the comprehensive plan update and King County’s housing and community development program indicates that their review of the GMA effects includes only one study that examines the historic change in housing prices.[24] This study graphs annual changes in housing prices against employment (a proxy for population growth) and housing supply. The factors associated with changes in the long term housing supply have not been studied. By correlating employment and housing supply with annual changes in housing prices, the GMPC study mixes short and long term effects. In the short run (year to year), the supply of housing is fixed; therefore, annual changes in housing prices can hardly exhibit a significant correlation with housing supply.
While Washington planners especially in Seattle and King County seem to have carefully monitored housing demand and its effect on prices, the above data indicates that housing supply (regulations) has also been associated with significant increases in housing prices. The analysis also highlights that any policy intervention at the municipal, county, or statewide level must be accompanied by strong follow up analyses regarding its impacts on housing prices. In addition, studies should be comparative so that the impact of regulations on Seattle can be evaluated by comparing results across cities with similar housing demand pressures in order to have a clear metric of evaluation.
As discussed in Figure 1, the optimal policy may be aimed at increasing or decreasing the price of housing. Growth management is often advocated because it allows for designed natural states in urban peripheries and increases construction/density in the urban core. Whether these incentives were sufficient to generate the required increase in housing is an empirical question that is answered by the speed of rising housing prices. Nearly two dozen studies in the past 2 decades associate rising prices with regulations (see Appendix 3).

8. Summary and Policy Implications

Using new, consistent, and comparable land use regulation data reveals that land use regulations are correlated with housing price increases across 250 major US cities. The data indicate that aside from demand effects, statewide regulations and growth management are associated with increases in housing prices. In addition, when courts reject challenges to municipal land use restrictions (which may have been created to adhere to statewide laws), the effects of regulations on housing prices are amplified. Finally, cost-increasing regulations at the municipal level are also found to impact housing prices.
The restrictiveness and the effects of land use regulations vary substantially across five cities in Washington State, ranging from an estimated increase of $203,000 in Seattle to $73,000 in Vancouver, WA. The largest share of this increase is not due to municipal regulations, but due to the effects of statewide regulations. When statewide regulations negate sprawl or limit building heights, they exacerbate agglomeration pressures at the city centers. Ultimately these dynamics are reflected in the increase in housing prices in the time period examined above.
Dollar cost estimates of regulations in terms of increased housing prices are derived by examining the change in housing prices from 1989 to 2006. This long term view is different from short term fluctuations that are often the focus of public debates. In the short run (a year or so), the supply of housing is fixed, so that short term analyses are by design unlikely to find a meaningful correlation between housing prices and supply over this time frame. The above results highlight that only a fraction of the change in housing prices is explained when supply side is ignored.
The analysis does not address whether more regulations are better, worse, or misguided. This would be a value judgment that requires the documentation of both costs and benefits of regulations. Ultimately, the increase in housing prices may be below or above citizens’ valuation of the absence of sprawl. To elicit a benefit valuation of regulations is beyond the scope of this research project. Economic methods to study the contingent valuation[25] are widespread in environmental economics, but they are time intensive (and costly) and infrequently used in the housing regulation literature to establish the benefits of regulations.[26] The alternative is to rely on the electorate. After being informed about the costs of regulations, voters can decide whether to support further regulations, or whether to abolish existing ones.
While this study details the private costs of regulations (the increased cost of housing), it does not include the social cost of regulations, since costs for changed commuting, parking and pollution patterns are not available. Also, while higher housing prices represent a windfall for sellers, they also constitute a redistribution from buyers to sellers as well as a reduction in housing affordability.[27] Land use regulations that increase housing prices also have a time dimension: current owners are the beneficiaries of such regulations, but their children and future migrants to the area bear the costs. This represents redistribution over time and generations, which may affect the location decisions of individuals and companies to limit productivity growth.[28] The design of land use policy is hampered by the complexity of the urban housing market that is difficult to model and predict (for economists and policy makers alike). It is therefore imperative to evaluate whether policies designed to maximize the citizens’ welfare actually achieve the policy goal without unintended side effects.

Funding Statement

This research received no external funding.

Acknowledgments

I thank Kriss Sjoblom, Dick Conway, Debora I. Dusselich, Kenneth J. Dueker, Hart Hodges, Richard Allen Nelson, Lillian Lyons, Marty Lyons, Catherine O'Donnell, and Bob Roseth for helpful comments.

Declaration of Competing Interest

The author claims that the manuscript is completely original. The author also declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix 1. Regression Diagnostics

If the regression model in equation (4) and its empirical implementation in Table 5 is missing vital explanatory variables, the coefficient estimates may be biased. Diagnostic tests exist to examine whether an explanatory variable may have been omitted, although it is systematically related to the variable of interest. Visual inspection of the residuals in Figure A1 shows a largely random pattern and provides no indication of an omitted explanatory variable (the R2 associated with Figure A1 is 0.0000). A more stringent test than the visual examination of the errors is to examine the normal probability plot for the residuals in Figure A2, to see whether the residuals are approximately normally distributed (e. g., random). Given Figure A2, it seems hard to argue that the residuals are not normally distributed.
After ascertaining that there is no obvious evidence for omitted variable bias, it is important to examine the validity of the assumed functional form. Malpezzi (1996) proposes a nonlinear relationship between housing prices and regulations, which is suggested by the visual inspection of his data. Having extended his sample from about 50 to 250 major cities seems to have removed the apparent nonlinearity – at least according to a visual inspection of Figures 2a-d, which seem to indicate linear rather than nonlinear relationships. The STATA ovtest routine tests for omitted variables by examining alternative specifications of the baseline model that also feature polynomials. Adding polynomials for regulations does not improve the regression. The STATA reset test for regression specification errors (Ramsey 1969) also shows no evidence for nonlinearities in regulations in the sample of 250 cities. Malpezzi (1996) also used the log of housing price, presumably to address heteroskedasticity in his sample. The Breusch-Pagan tests for the constancy of the error variance; the obtained critical value indicates that the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected.
app--1-regression-diagnostics-2
Figure A1. Prediction Errors.
Figure A1. Prediction Errors.
app--1-regression-diagnostics-2
app--1-regression-diagnostics-3
Figure A2. Residuals’ Normal Probability Plot.
Figure A2. Residuals’ Normal Probability Plot.
app--1-regression-diagnostics-3

Appendix 2

Table A1. Summary Statistics.
table
Table A1. Summary Statistics.
Variable Description/Source Variable ID Observations Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
Approval Delay Index Permit and Zoning Approval Delay Index. See also Gyourko et al. (2008) adi 250 5.993556 3.784825 1.333333 29.38889
Executive and Legislative Rating The level of activity in the executive and legislative branches over the past ten years that is directed toward enacting greater statewide land use restrictions. See Gyourko et al. (2008) execrating 253 2.304348 0.6888143 1 3
Real Housing Price 1989 housing prices (median owner occupied, 2006 dollars. Census) medval89_r 253 168220.2 105956 41132.74 570818.4
Housing Price 2006 housing prices (median owner occupied, 2006 dollars. Census) medval06 253 259140.3 169130.6 60900 806700
Real income growth Average annual compound growth of real median household income 1989-2006 (Census, 2006 dollars) mi_gr 253 -0.0024926 0.0075162 -0.0235441 0.0350843
Real Housing Price Growth Average annual compound growth of the real price of the median owner occupied house 1989-2006 (2006 dollars, Census). mv_gr 253 0.0234268 0.0148009 -0.0256737 0.0683899
Density 2006 Population (Census) / 2000 Land area (Census) person_sqm06 253 4521.534 4765.727 164.2102 53347.4
Population growth Average annual compound growth of the population 1989-2006. (Census) pop_gr 253 0.0150111 0.0210629 -0.0140978 0.1097826
State Court Involvement Index Judicial land use environment. Tendency of courts to uphold or restrain municipal land-use regulations See Gyourko et al. (2008) scii 253 2.245059 0.593638 1 3
State Legislature Involvement The degree of involvement of the state legislature in affecting the residential building activities and/or growth management procedures of a jurisdiction. See Gyourko et al. (2008) stateleg 247 2.194332 1.068149 1 5
Wharton Residential Land Use Regulatory Index (“Wharton Index”) See Gyourko et al. (2008) wrluri 246 0.0779213 0.9386766 -1.9241 3.625351

Appendix 3

app--3-0
Table A2. Stringency of Land Use Regulations in the Wharton Sample for Washington State.
Table A2. Stringency of Land Use Regulations in the Wharton Sample for Washington State.
app--3-0
(As Reported by City Planning Directors to Wharton)
Table A3.1. Results From Comparative Studies of Land Use Restrictions and Housing Prices.
table
Table A3.1. Results From Comparative Studies of Land Use Restrictions and Housing Prices.
Study Authors Year Cities/Regions Effects
1 Anthony 2006 FL Increase in prices attributable to statewide growth management.
2 Glaeser, Schuetz, Ward 2006 187 Communities in Eastern MA 23-36 percent increase in prices (about $156,000) due to regulations.
3 Somerville / Meyer 2006 44 Metro Areas 20% higher price elasticities and 45% lower housing starts in more regulated areas.
4 Xing et al. 2006 54 Metro Areas Increase in prices due to growth management and development restrictiveness. Seattle: 15% increase in prices due to growth management tools
5 Chan 2004 97 Metro Areas 44.8% to -3.9% increases in price in cities with urban growth boundaries.
6 Downs 2002 86 Metro Areas Increase in prices 1990-2000, 1990-94, 1990-96 due to Urban Growth Boundary. Not significant 1994-2000, 1996-2000, so UGB increases housing prices combined with stimulated housing demand.
7 Glaeser/Gyourko 2002 40 Metro Areas $50-$700,000 increase in prices due to zoning restrictions. (Seattle: +$200,000)
8 Malpezzi 2002 55 Metro Areas Increase in prices due to regulations, controlling for High Tech Locations
9 Staley/Gilroy 2001 OR, FL, WA 15% increase in prices attributed to growth management.
10 Luger/Temkin 2000 NC, NJ $40-80,000 increase in prices of new homes due to regulations
11 Phillips et al 2000 37 Metro Areas Increase in prices due to regulation index and weak evidence for urban growth boundary effect. But impact is low (less than $10,000 per unit).
12 Green 1999 Waukesha, WI 8% increase in prices due to zoning and permitting restrictions
13 Malpezzi, et al. 1998 55 Metro Areas 9-46% increase in prices due to regulations
14 Malpezzi 1996 60 Metro Areas 51% increase in prices due to regulations
15 Thorson 1996 10 Metro Areas Increase in prices due to “zoning monopolies”
16 Cho/Linneman 1993 Fairfax, VA Increase in prices due to minimum lot sizes. No increase in prices due to residential restrictions
17 Downs 1992 San Diego, CA 54% increase in prices due to growth management
18 Pollakowski/ Wachter 1990 Montgomery, MD 27% increase in prices (price elasticity: 0.275) due to regulatory restrictiveness
19 Katz/Rosen 1987/1 63 CA Metros 17-38% increase in prices due to growth management
20 Landis 1986 CA 35-45% increase in prices in growth controlled areas
21 Schwartz et al. 1986 Sacramento, Davis 9% increase in prices due to growth controls
22 Segal/ Srinivasan 1985 51 Metro Areas 20% increase in prices in growth restricted areas
Table A3.2. Empirical Studies on the Impact of Growth Regulation on Housing Prices. Surveyed by Nelson et al. (2004)
table
Table A3.2. Empirical Studies on the Impact of Growth Regulation on Housing Prices. Surveyed by Nelson et al. (2004)
Study Authors Year Cities/Regions Impact
Luger and Temkin 2000 New Jersey, North Carolina Yes
Green 1999 Suburban Wisconsin Yes
Porter et al. 1996 Montgomery County, Maryland Yes
Beaton and Pollock 1992 Chesapeake Bay, Maryland Yes
Downs 1992 San Diego County Yes
Parsons 1992 Chesapeake Bay, Maryland Yes
Beaton 1991 New Jersey Pinelands Yes
Guidry, Shilling, and Sirmans 1991 National Yes
Shilling 1991 National Yes
Dale-Johnson and Kim 1990 California Coast Yes
Pollakowski and Wachter 1990 Montgomery County, Maryland Yes
Rose 1989 National Yes
Chambers and Diamond 1988 National Yes
Nelson 1988 Washington County, Oregon Yes
Katz and Rosen 1987 San Francisco Bay Area Yes
Landis 1986 Sacramento, Fresno, San Jose, California Yes
Nelson 1986 Salem, Oregon Yes
Zorn et al. 1986 Davis, California Yes
Black and Hoben 1985 National Yes
Knaap 1985 Portland, Oregon Yes
Segal and Srinivasan 1985 National Yes
Dowall 1984 Santa Rosa, Napa, California Yes
Frech and Lafferty 1984 California Coast Yes
Dowall and Landis 1982 San Francisco Bay Area Yes
Mercer and Morgan 1982 Santa Barbara County, California Yes
Schwartz et al. 1981, 84 Petaluma, Santa Rosa, Rohnert Park, CA Yes
Elliot 1981 California Yes
Correll, Lillydahl, and Singell 1978 Boulder, Colorado Yes
Real Estate Research Corp 1978 St. Louis County, Missouri Yes
Urban Land Institute 1977 National Yes
Richardson 1976 Dover Township, New Jersey Yes
Peterson 1973 Fairfax County, Virginia Yes
Phillips and Goodstein 2000 Portland, Oregon No
Glickfield and Levine 1992 California No
Knaap and Nelson 1992 Portland, Oregon No
Landis 1992 California No
Downs 2002 Portland, Oregon Mixed
Lowry and Ferguson 1992 Sacramento, Orlando, Nashville Mixed
Miller 1986 Boulder, Colorado Mixed
Gleeson 1978 Brooklyn Park, Minnesota Mixed

Notes

1
At times public opinion and policy makers seem to be taken aback that housing prices depend on regulations. It is the expressed purpose and design of regulations to influence the housing supply. The conceptual framework in Section 3 clarifies that housing prices may rise or fall due to regulations. ↑
2
Nelson et al. (2004) are often cited as providing academic evidence that regulations do not affect housing prices. Even cursory reading of the executive summary reveals that such statements are at odds with the conclusions of their paper. The authors present only their perspectives on previous housing studies, not original work. Connerly (2004) summarizes the evidence surveyed in Nelson et al. (2004); Appendix 3 Table A3.2 reproduces Connelly’s Table. ↑
3
Based on Census data for median real price of owner-occupied housing described in detail below. ↑
4
The data is based on a survey of 11 real estate experts who ranked land use restrictiveness of 30 metropolitan areas on a 10-point scale. Instead of a single regulation criterion, the survey covered 6 broad areas of land use regulations. The Urban Land Institute data covers: 1) wet land management, 2) power plant regulation, 3) critical areas and wilderness, 4) strip mining, 5) flood plains, and 6) tax incentives. The variable is unfortunately binary, indicating only whether regulations exist or not. ↑
5
Unfortunately, communication with the authors of the study indicates that this data has been lost. ↑
6
Malpezzi (1996) mentions the following externalities that raise the social cost of housing: “1. Congestion. Building additional housing units in a community generally increases traffic locally (although it may reduce total commuting distance). 2. Environmental costs. Building additional housing units may reduce the local supply of green space; reduce air quality; and increase pressure on local water, sanitation, and solid waste collection systems (although again the global impact is less clear). 3. Infrastructure costs. Costs may rise as communities invest to grapple with environmental problems and congestion. Effects will depend on whether the particular community has yet exhausted economies of scale in the provision of each type of infrastructure. 4. Fiscal effects. In addition to the obvious effects from the above, demand may increase for local public services (education, fire and police protection, new residents believing libraries should be open on Sundays in contradiction to local custom). New residents may or may not pay sufficient additional taxes to cover the marginal costs. 5. Neighborhood composition effects. New households may be different from existing households. If existing households prefer living with people of similar incomes, or the same race, they will perceive costs if people different from them move in.” ↑
7
Malpezzi (1996) points to “1. Productivity and employment. A well-functioning housing market is generally required for a well-functioning labor market. In particular, labor mobility may be adversely affected and wages may rise to uncompetitive levels if housing markets are not elastic. 2. Health benefits. At least at some level, less crowding and improved sanitation may be associated with lower rates of mortality and morbidity. 3. Racial and economic integration. One person’s external cost may be another person’s external benefit if some households value heterogeneity, for themselves or for others. For those particularly concerned about employment of low-income households or minorities, concerns about the productivity and employment effects mentioned earlier are reinforced. 4. Externalities associated with homeownership. More housing units or lower housing prices may be associated with greater opportunity for homeownership. Homeownership has been argued to be associated with many desirable social outcomes, ranging from improved maintenance of the housing stock to greater political stability.” ↑
8
Pogodzinski and Sass (1991) provide a structured review of diverse approaches to modeling the effect of housing supply on housing prices. They highlight the multitude of different regulation criteria that have been employed in regional studies, which emphasizes how tenuous the generalizations are that link “regulations” to housing prices, based on individual city studies. Green et al. (2005) provide the most sophisticated empirical implementation of a theory based housing supply model. Although they control for regulations, it is not the objective of their paper to quantify the effects of regulations on housing prices. ↑
9
For a complete discussion of growth vs. level regressions, see Caselli et al. (1996). ↑
10
Since a reduced form is estimated, coefficients are not exact supply and demand elasticities (in the sense that it is impossible to isolate exact supply and demand effects of, for example, a change in income). The coefficients do provide an estimate of the impact on prices due to changes in the right-hand-side variables. When the terms “demand” and “supply” are used below, they thus refer to variables that are associated primarily with demand and supply effects. ↑
11
At times the relationship between prices and regulations is seen to be nonlinear (e.g., Malpezzi, 1996). This possible specification is discussed in the robustness section below. ↑
12
The insight that different variants of hedonic regression techniques generate fundamentally different answers dates back to at least Triplett and McDonald (1977; 150, see Diewert 2003). In markets with finite numbers of goods, Pakes (2003) details the various biases of the hedonic regressions and outlines necessary conditions when proper hedonic indices can be constructed. ↑
13
The unit of analysis is the “city” for the Census and the “metropolitan area” for S&P data. Therefore the data is not directly comparable (for example, Detroit City experienced a 4 percent greater nominal annual growth in housing prices than the Detroit metropolitan area). Nevertheless it is important to report that the quality adjusted S&P data features an even greater correlation with the Wharton Index than the Census data. ↑
14
Since the low value for the Wharton Index is -2.12, and the maximum is 4.65 in the dataset, one can substitute for these values in column 2 of Table 5 and find that the annual compounded growth rates in highly regulated cities is 2.41 percent higher than the growth rate in a city with the most permissive land use regulations. Over 17 years this implies that the difference in the annual compounded growth rate raises the level of housing prices in the most regulated city 50 percent above the level of housing prices in the least regulated cities. ↑
15
Such delays are defined by 8 indicators that measure the average duration of the review process, the time between application for rezoning and issuance of a building permit, the time between application for subdivision approval and the issuance of a building permit conditional on proper zoning being in place. Each indicator considers three types of projects: i) Small single-family projects involving fewer than 50 units, ii) Larger single-family developments with more than 50 units, iii) Multifamily projects of indeterminate size. ↑
16
All regressors except one are found to be highly robust to alternative specifications and iterations of the stepwise procedure. The Approval Delays subindex of the Wharton Index is sensitive to the inclusion of other cost increasing measures, for example, impact fees or lot development costs. The Approval Delay subindex was maintained, because of its broad interpretation and because it represents the largest possible data sample (several alternative, cost increasing measures reduce the size of the sample substantially). ↑
17
These are the only Washington State cities contained in the sample of 250 major cities. Appendix 2 reports the regulatory data for all 50 cities in Washington State that responded to the Wharton survey. If a city is included in Appendix 2, but not included in the sample of 250 cities, it is because the 2006 Census data was not available. ↑
18
Note that the regression accounts for both population growth and density (population per area (in sq. miles)), which is particularly important in Vancouver, WA, which grew substantially in both dimensions over the period. ↑
19
Glaeser and Gyourko (2002) report only the cost increase per square foot. O’Tool (2002) then calculates quarter acre lot prices based on the difference between Glaeser and Gyourko’s imputed land cost and their estimated price of land specification. Kent, Vancouver, Everett and Tacoma were not in their sample. ↑
20
Recall that a perfect correlation of the result in the two studies would imply a correlation coefficient of 1. ↑
21
See Lillydahl and Singell (1987), Pogodzinski and Sass, 1991, Ihlanfeldt (2004), Xing et al. (2006), Landis et al. (2002), and especially Quigley and Rosenthal (2005). ↑
22
The “GMA requires state and local governments to manage Washington’s growth by identifying and protecting critical areas and natural resource lands, designating urban growth areas, preparing comprehensive plans and implementing them through capital investments and development regulations” (see http://www.gmhb.wa.gov/gma/index.html) ↑
23
All cities that are covered by a GMA, that is. In Washington, for example, the GMA was a state mandate that local governments had to follow - where it applied. Originally only 18 counties were required to plan and 11 more opted in. The remaining counties were exempted from portions of the GMA. ↑
24
See Figures 14 and 15 in the staff report presented to the GMPC on March 28th, 2001. http://www.metrokc.gov/ddes/gmpc/ag_rpts2001.shtm
25
Contingent valuation is a survey-based method to assign monetary valuations to goods and services (in this case land use regulations) that cannot be bought and sold in the marketplace. ↑
27
Housing is generally classified as affordable when renters or owners pay less than 30% of their income in rent or mortgage. For evidence on changes in affordable housing see Crellin (2006), King County (2004) and National Low Income Housing Coalition (2007). Quigley and Raphael (2005) survey the literature and cite one paper that examines the effects of land use regulations on affordable housing (Malpezzi and Green, 1996).
28
See van Nieuwerburgh and Weill (2007). ↑

References

  1. American Institute of Planners (AIP), (1976) Survey of State Land Use Planning Activity. Report to the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. Washington, DC. [Google Scholar ]
  2. Beasley, S. D., W. G. Workman and N.A. Williams, (1986), Estimating amenity values of urban fringe farmland: a contingent valuation approach: note, Growth and Change 17, (4), pp:70–78. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2257.1986.tb00067.x [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  3. Black, J. T. and J. Hoben, (1985), Land price inflation and affordable housing, Urban Geography 6, (1), pp: 27-49. https://doi.org/10.2747/0272-3638.6.1.27 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  4. Breffle, W. S., Morey, E. R. and T. S. Lodder, (1998), Using Contingent Valuation to Estimate a Neighborhood’s Willingness to Pay to Preserve Undeveloped Urban Land, Urban Studies 35, (4), pp:715–727. https://doi.org/10.1080/0042098984718 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  5. Breusch, T. and A. Pagan, (1979), A Simple Test for Heteroskedasticity and Random Coefficient Variation, Econometrica, 47, pp:1287-1294. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911963 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  6. Brueckner, J. K., (2007), Government Land-Use Interventions: An Economic Analysis, Urban Land Markets, 3-23. [Google Scholar ]
  7. Carson, J., (2006), Housing Costs in the CPI, What Are We Measuring, Business Economics, January, 41, 59–68. https://doi.org/10.2145/20060108 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  8. Caselli, F., G. Esquivel and F. Lefort, (1996), Reopening the Convergence Debate: A New Look at Cross-Country Growth Empirics, Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 363–389. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00141044 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  9. Chan S. (2004), Drawing the Line: The Effect of Urban Growth Boundaries on Housing Prices in the San Francisco Bay Area, Stanford University Working Paper [Google Scholar ]
  10. Cho M. and P.A. Linneman, (1993), Interjurisdictional Spillover Effects of Land Use Regulations, Journal of Housing Research, Volume 4, 1, 131-163. https://www.jstor.org/stable/24832756 [Google Scholar ]
  11. Connerly, C. E., (2004), Smart Growth Opportunity or Threat for Affordable Housing? Florida State University Working Paper, published (without tables) in Incentives, Regulations and Plans: The Role of States and Nation-states in Smart Growth Planning G. Knaap, H. A. Haccou, K. J. Clifton, J. W. Frece eds Edward Elgar Publishing (2007). [Google Scholar ]
  12. Crellin G. A. Daheim and R. Nelson, (2006), Washington’s Growth Management Act at 15: How has Affordable Housing Fared? Washington Center for Real Estate Research Working Paper (106). [Google Scholar ]
  13. Diewert, E., (2003), Hedonic Regressions: A Review of Some Unresolved Issues, presentation at the Ottawa Group Meeting on Price Indices, Paris. [Google Scholar ]
  14. Downs, A., (1992), Regulatory Barriers to Affordable Housing, Journal of the American Planning Association, 58, 4, pp. 419-22. [Google Scholar ]
  15. Downs, A., (2002), Have Housing Prices Risen Faster in Portland Than Elsewhere, Housing Policy Debate, Vol 13 (1). https://doi.org/10.1080/10511482.2002.9521432 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  16. Duranton, G. and D. Puga, (2004), Micro-foundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies, Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, 4, 48, 2063-2117. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0080(04)80005-1 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  17. Ervin, K., (2006), Judges Reject Local Vote On Critical Areas Rules, Seattle Times December 22. [Google Scholar ]
  18. Foster, D. D. and A. Summers, (2005), Current State Legislative and Judicial Profiles on Land-Use Regulations in the U.S., Wharton Real Estate Center WP No. 512. [Google Scholar ]
  19. Geoghegan, J., (2002), The Value of Open Spaces in Residential Land Use, Land Use Policy, 19, (1), pp. 91-98. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0264-8377(01)00040-0 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  20. Glaeser, E. L. and J Gyourko, (2002), Zoning’s Steep Price, Regulation. 25(3) pp: 24-31 [Google Scholar ]
  21. Glaeser, E. L., (2004), Housing Supply, NBER Reporter Spring [Google Scholar ]
  22. Glaeser, E. L., (2007), The Economic Approach to Cities, NBER Working Paper 13696. https://doi.org/ 10.3386/w13696 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  23. Glaeser, E. L., J Gyourko and R. Saks, (2005), Why Is Manhattan So Expensive? Regulation and the Rise in Housing Prices, Journal of Law and Economics 48, (2), 331-369. https://doi.org/10.1086/429979 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  24. Glaeser, E. L., J. Schuetz and B. Ward, (2006), Regulation and the Rise of Housing Prices in Greater Boston, White Paper, Rappaport Institute Harvard University [Google Scholar ]
  25. Glaeser, E. L., J. Schuetz and B. Ward, (2006), The Price is (Not) Right, Commonwealth (Growth and Development Extra), pp. 99-102 [Google Scholar ]
  26. Green R. K., S. Malpezzi, and S. K. Mayo, (2005), Metropolitan-Specific Estimates of the Price Elasticity of Supply of Housing, and Their Sources, American Economic Review, Vol. 95(2), 334-339. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282805774670077 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  27. Green, R. K., (1999), Land Use Regulation and the Price of Ho using in a Suburban Wisconsin County, Journal of Housing Economics, 8(2):144-159 (June). [Google Scholar ]
  28. Guidry, K. A., J. D. Shilling, and C. F. Sirmans, (1991), An Econometric Analysis of Variation in Urban Residential Land Prices and the Adoption of Land-Use Controls, University of Wisconsin Working Paper [Google Scholar ]
  29. Gyourko, J and A. Summers, (2006), Residential Land Use Regulation in the Philadelphia MSA, Wharton Working Papers [Google Scholar ]
  30. Gyourko, J., A. Saiz, and A. Summers, (2008), A New Measure of the Local Regulatory Environment for Housing Markets: The Wharton Residential Land Use Regulatory Index, Urban Economics. 45, 3. https://doi.org/10.1177/0042098007087341 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  31. Heravi, S. and M. Silver, (2002), On the Stability of Hedonic Coefficients and their Implications for Quality Adjusted Price Change Measurement, presented at the Joint NBER and CRIW Measurement Workshop [Google Scholar ]
  32. Ihlanfeldt, K. R., (2004), Exclusionary Land-use Regulations within Suburban Communities: A Review of the Evidence and Policy Prescriptions, Urban Studies, 41(2), 261-283. https://doi.org/10.1080/004209803200165244 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  33. Katz L. and K. Rosen, (1984), The Effects of Land Use Controls on Housing Prices, UC Berkeley, Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics, 1984 [Google Scholar ]
  34. Katz L. and K. Rosen, (1987), The Interjurisdictional Effects of Growth Controls on Housing Prices, Journal of Law and Economics 56, 1, 149-160. https://doi.org/10.1086/467133 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  35. King County, (2004), Annual Bulletin Tracking Housing Costs in King County, King County's Budget Office, Demographics Section [Google Scholar ]
  36. Landis J. D., L. Deng and M. Reilly, (2002), Growth Management Revisited: A Reassessment of its Efficacy, Price Effects and Impacts on Metropolitan Growth Patterns, UC Berkeley: Institute of Urban and Regional Development Working Paper 02. http://hdl.handle.net/10419/23602 [Google Scholar ]
  37. Landis, J. D., (1986), Land Regulation and the Price of New Housing: Lesson from Three California Cities, Journal of the American Planning Association 52(1), 9-21. https://doi.org/10.1080/01944368608976855 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  38. Langston, J., (2005), Critical Areas Ordinance' Provokes Bitter 'Rural vs. Urban' Dispute, Seattle Post-Intelligencer, November 16. [Google Scholar ]
  39. Levine, N., (1999), The Effect of Local Growth Controls on Regional Housing Production and Population Redistribution in California, Urban Studies, 36 (12), 2047–68. https://doi.org/10.1080/0042098992539 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  40. Linneman P. A. Summer, H. Buist and N. Brooks, (1990), The State of Local Growth Management Wharton Real Estate Center Working Paper 81 [Google Scholar ]
  41. Luger, M. and K. M. Temki, (2000), Red Tape and Housing Costs: How Regulation Affects New Residential Development, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 21, 4, 715-717. https://www.jstor.org/stable/3326021 [Google Scholar ]
  42. Malpezzi, S. and R.K. Green (1996), What Has Happened to the Bottom of the US Housing Market? Urban Studies, 33, (10), 1807-1820. https://doi.org/10.1080/0042098966385 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  43. Malpezzi, S., (1996), Housing Prices, Externalities, and Regulation in U.S. Metropolitan Areas, Journal of Housing Research, 7, (2), 209-241. https://www.jstor.org/stable/24832860 [Google Scholar ]
  44. Malpezzi, S., G. Chun and R. Green, (1998), New Place-to-Place Housing Price Indexes for U.S. Metropolitan Areas, and Their Determinants: An Application of Housing Indicators, Real Estate Economics, 26(2), 235-75. https://doi.org/10.1111/1540-6229.00745 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  45. Mankiw N. G., and D. N. Weil, (1991), The Baby Boom, The Baby Bust and the Housing Market. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 21(4), 573-579. https://doi.org/10.1016/0166-0462(89)90005-7 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  46. National Low Income Housing Coalition (NLIHC), (2006), National Low Income Housing Coalition Annual Report, http://www.nlihc.org/oor/oor2006/ [Google Scholar ]
  47. Nelson, A. C., R. Pendall, C. J. Dawkins, and G. J. Knaap, (2004), The Link between Growth Management and Housing Affordability: The Academic Evidence, in Anthony Downs, ed., Growth Management and Affordable Housing: Do They Conflict? Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 117-158. [Google Scholar ]
  48. O’Sullivan, A., (2003), Urban Economics, 5th Edition Boston: McGraw-Hill. [Google Scholar ]
  49. O’Toole, R., (2002), Land-use Regulation Makes Housing less Affordable, Harvard Study Finds, Environment News, November 1 [Google Scholar ]
  50. Pakes, Ariel, (2003), A Reconsideration Of Hedonic Price Indexes With An Application To PC's, American Economic Review, 93(5), 1578-1614. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803322655455 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  51. Phillips, J. and E. Goodstein, (2000), Growth Management and Housing Prices: The Case of Portland, Oregon, Contemporary Economic Policy, 18(3):334-344. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7287.2000.tb00030.x [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  52. Pogodzinski, J. N. and T. R. Sass, (1991), Measuring the Effects of Municipal Zoning Regulation: A Survey, Urban Studies, 28, 597-621. https://doi.org/10.1080/00420989120080681 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  53. Pollakowski H. O. and S. M. Wachter, (1990), The Effects of Land-Use Constraints on Housing Prices, Land Economics, 66, 3, 315-324. https://doi.org/10.2307/3146732 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  54. Postrel, V., (2007), The Tale of Town Homes, Atlantic Monthly, Vol 300, 4. [Google Scholar ]
  55. Poterba, J. M., (1984), Tax Subsidies to Owner-Occupied Housing: An Asset-Market Approach, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99, 4, 729-752. https://doi.org/10.2307/1883123 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  56. Quigley J.M. and S. Raphael., (2005), Regulation and the High Cost of Housing in California, American Economic Review, 95, (3) 323-328. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282805774670293 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  57. Quigley, J. M., and L. Rosenthal, (2005), The Effects of Land Use Regulation on the Price of Housing: What do We Know? What Can We Learn, Cityscape, 8, 69–138. https://www.jstor.org/stable/20868572 [Google Scholar ]
  58. Ramsey, J. B., (1969), Tests for Specification Errors In Classical Least-Squares Regression Analysis, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 31, 350-71. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2517-6161.1969.tb00796.x [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  59. Ready, R. C., M. C. Berger and G. Blomquist, (1997), Measuring Benefits From Farmland: Hedonic Pricing vs. Contingent Valuation, Growth and Change 28, (4), pp. 438–458. [Google Scholar ]
  60. Rosenthal, Stuart S., (1999), Housing Supply: The Other Half of the Market, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 18(1), pp. 5–8. [Google Scholar ]
  61. Schwartz, S, P.M. Zorn and D.E. Hanen, (1986), Research Design Issues and Pitfalls in Growth Control Studies, Land Economics, 62, 3, 223-233. https://doi.org/10.2307/3146388 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  62. Seattle Times, (2008), That 500,000 Rambler, Editorial Board Opinion February 19, 2008. [Google Scholar ]
  63. Segal, D. and P, Srinivasan, (1985), The Impact of Suburban Growth Restrictions on U.S. Residential Land Value, Urban Geography 6, (1), pp: 14-26. [Google Scholar ]
  64. Singell L. D. and J. H. Lillydahl, (1987), An Empirical Examination of the Effect of Impact Fees on the Housing Market, Land Economics, 66, 1, 82-92. https://doi.org/10.2307/3146685 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  65. Somerville C. T. and C. J. Mayer, (2003), Government Regulation and Changes in the Affordable Housing Stock, Economic Policy Review, June 2003 45-6. https://ssrn.com/abstract=790506 [Google Scholar ]
  66. Staley S. R., and L. C. Gilroy, (2001), Smart Growth and Housing Affordability: Evidence from Statewide Planning Laws, Reason Public Policy Institute. [Google Scholar ]
  67. Summers, L.H., (1981), Inflation, The Stock Market and Owner-Occupied Housing, American Economic Review, vol. 71(2), pages 429-34. [Google Scholar ]
  68. Thorson, J. A., (1996), An Examination of the Monopoly Zoning Hypothesis, Land Economics 72(1):43-55. https://doi.org/10.2307/3147156 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  69. Triplett, J. E. and R. J. McDonald, (1977), Assessing the Quality Error in Output Measures: The Case of Refrigerators, Review of Income and Wealth 23:2, 137-156. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4991.1977.tb00008.x [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  70. Van Nieuwerburgh, S. and P. O. Weill, (2010), Why Has House Price Dispersion Gone Up? The Review of Economic Studies, 77, 4, 1567–1606, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-937X.2010.00611.x [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
  71. Xing, X, D. J. Hartzell and D. R. Godschalk, (2006), Land Use Regulations and Housing Markets in Large Metropolitan Areas, Journal of Housing Research, 15 (1), 1-26. https://doi.org/10.1080/10835547.2004.12091964 [Google Scholar ][Crossref]
Table 1. Prices of Housing Units Relative to Their New Construction Costs.
Table 1. Prices of Housing Units Relative to Their New Construction Costs.
1989 1999 1989 1999
Housing valued 90% construction cost Housing valued 90% construction cost Housing valued 140% construction cost Housing valued 140% construction cost
San Francisco Suburbs, Calif. 1% 2% 98% 97%
San Francisco, Calif. 0% 4% 97% 96%
Anaheim Suburbs, Calif. 25% 3% 96% 96%
Anaheim, Calif. 0% 0% 100% 93%
San Diego, Calif. 7% 3% 88% 93%
Oxnard Suburbs, Calif. 0% 4% 100% 93%
Seattle Suburbs, Wash. 2% 1% 72% 90%
Los Angeles, Calif. 2% 4% 93% 89%
Los Angeles Suburbs, Calif. 4% 4% 91% 89%
San Diego Suburbs, Calif. 4% 5% 92% 88%
Denver, Colo. 4% 8% 60% 86%
Seattle, Wash. 6% 2% 49% 86%
Boston Suburbs, Mass. 1% 2% 87% 86%
Salt Lake City Suburbs, Utah 10% 2% 22% 86%
Fort Lauderdale Suburbs, Fla. 0% 0% 76% 85%
Albuquerque, N.M. 2% 3% 82% 83%
Raleigh, N.C. 6% 2% 81% 81%
New York Suburbs, N.Y. 3% 9% 85% 78%
Phoenix Suburbs, Ariz. 2% 0% 65% 76%
Riverside Suburbs, Calif. 5% 2% 87% 76%
Chicago Suburbs, Ill. 6% 5% 67% 74%
Miami Suburbs, Fla. 5% 0% 72% 73%
Sacramento, Calif. 0% 3% 55% 72%
Newark Suburbs, N.J. 1% 1% 96% 72%
Sacramento Suburbs, Calif. 3% 5% 83% 72%
Austin, Tex. 0% 6% 46% 71%
Greensboro, N.C. 13% 0% 59% 69%
Norfolk, Va. 1% 2% 87% 66%
Tampa Suburbs, Fla. 3% 5% 57% 66%
Phoenix, Ariz. 2% 5% 69% 65%
Tucson, Ariz. 6% 4% 43% 61%
Baltimore Suburbs, Md. 5% 1% 66% 61%
Columbus Suburbs, Ohio 12% 3% 47% 61%
New Orleans Suburbs, La. 10% 6% 53% 61%
Orlando Suburbs, Fla. 3% 4% 70% 61%
Atlanta Suburbs, Ga. 3% 6% 67% 58%
Cleveland Suburbs, Ohio 15% 5% 23% 58%
Detroit Suburbs, Mich. 24% 8% 26% 58%
New Orleans, La. 2% 3% 49% 57%
Nashville-Davidson, Tenn. 2% 5% 69% 56%
New York, N.Y. 4% 11% 81% 56%
Birmingham Suburbs, Ala. 10% 12% 56% 53%
Milwaukee Suburbs, Wis. 5% 8% 39% 53%
Dallas Suburbs, Tex. 3% 6% 58% 52%
Tampa, Fla. 9% 13% 43% 49%
Fort Worth Suburbs, Tex. 9% 9% 59% 49%
Wichita, Kans. 18% 13% 21% 48%
Dallas, Tex. 6% 13% 56% 47%
Cincinnati Suburbs, Ohio 10% 10% 29% 47%
Philadelphia Suburbs, Pa. 3% 11% 78% 47%
Las Vegas, Nev. 0% 3% 29% 45%
Chicago, Ill. 20% 16% 28% 44%
Jacksonville, Fla. 8% 11% 55% 43%
Minneapolis Suburbs, Minn. 8% 5% 29% 43%
Oklahoma City, Okla. 13% 16% 30% 41%
Little Rock, Ark. 9% 8% 36% 40%
Albany Suburbs, N.Y. 6% 0% 63% 40%
Tulsa, Okla. 7% 8% 36% 38%
St. Louis Suburbs, Mo. 11% 21% 34% 34%
Kansas City Suburbs, Mo. 15% 5% 22% 33%
Houston Suburbs, Tex. 23% 8% 24% 31%
Minneapolis, Minn. 22% 20% 21% 30%
Columbus, Ohio 33% 12% 18% 29%
Fort Worth, Tex. 12% 26% 40% 29%
El Paso, Tex. 5% 2% 34% 28%
Rochester Suburbs, N.Y. 1% 9% 63% 28%
Baltimore, Md. 18% 30% 41% 27%
Houston, Tex. 25% 25% 40% 27%
San Antonio, Tex. 12% 30% 48% 26%
Toledo, Ohio 27% 40% 16% 23%
figure-1
Figure 1. Case 1: Cost Externalities Exist; Optimal Regulation is Imposed.
Figure 1. Case 1: Cost Externalities Exist; Optimal Regulation is Imposed.
figure-1
Table 2. Land Use Variables Collected in the Wharton Land Use Database.
Table 2. Land Use Variables Collected in the Wharton Land Use Database.
Variable Name Value Explanation
1 Local local council involvement in regulation (1-not at all, 5-very)
2 pressure community pressure involvement in regulation (1-not at all, 5-very)
3 countyleg county legislature involvement in regulation (1-not at all, 5-very)
4 Stateleg state legislature involvement in regulation (1-not at all, 5-very)
5 localcourts local courts involvement in regulation (1-not at all, 5-very)
6 statecourts state courts involvement in regulation (1-not at all, 5-very)
7 commission planning commission approval required for rezoning, 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by superm
8 loczoning local zoning board approval required for rezoning, 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by superma
9 Council local council approval required for rezoning, 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by supermajorit
10 cntyboard county board approval required for rezoning, 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by supermajority
11 cntyzoning county zoning board approval required for rezoning, 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by superm
12 envboard environmental review board approval required for rezoning, 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by
13 commission_no~z planning commission approval required (norezoning), 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by superm
14 Council_norez local council approval required (norezoning), 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by supermajorit
15 cntyboard_norez county board approval required (norezoning), 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by supermajority
16 envboard_norez environ review board approval required (norezoning), 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by super
17 publhlth_norez public health off approval required (norezoning), 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by supermaj
18 dsgnrev_norez design review board approval required (norezoning), 0=no, 1=yes, 2=yes by superm
19 sfulandsupply supply of land importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
20 mfulandsupply supply of land importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
21 sfudensrestr density restrictions importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
22 mfudensrestr density restrictions importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
23 sfuimpact impact fees/exactions importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
24 mfuimpact impact fees/exactions importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
25 sfucouncil council opposition importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
26 mfucouncil council opposition importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
27 sfucitizen citizen opposition importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
28 mfucitizen citizen opposition importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
29 sfulengthzoning length zoning process importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
30 mfulengthzoning length zoning process importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
31 sfulengthpermit length permit process importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
32 mfulengthpermit length permit process importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
33 sfulengthdvlp length development process importance (single family) 1-not at all, 5-very
34 mfulengthdvlp length development process importance (multi family) 1-not at all, 5-very
35 sfupermitlimit sf annual permit limit, 0=no, 1=yes
36 mfupermitlimit mf annual permit limit, 0=no, 1=yes
37 Sfuconstrlimit sf annual construction units limit, 0=no, 1=yes
38 mfuconstrlimit mf annual construction units limit, 0=no, 1=yes
39 mfudwelllimit mf dwelling limit, 0=no, 1=yes
40 mfudwellunitl~t num. of units in mf dwelling limit, 0=no, 1=yes
41 minlotsize min lot size requirement, 0=no, 1=yes
42 minlotsize_lh~e <=0.5 acre minlotsize requirement, 0=no, 1=yes
43 minlotsize_mh~e >0.5 acre minlotsize requirement, 0=no, 1=yes
44 minlotsize_on~e >1 acre minlotsize requirement, 0=no, 1=yes
45 minlotsize_tw~s >2 acres minlotsize requirement, 0=no, 1=yes
46 affordable affordable housing requirement, 0=no, 1=yes
47 sfusupply sf zoned land supply compared to demand, 1=far more, 5=far less
48 mfusupply mf zoned land supply compared to demand, 1=far more, 5=far less
49 commsupply commercially zoned land supply compared to demand, 1=far more, 5=far less
50 indsupply industrially zoned land supply compared to demand, 1=far more, 5=far less
51 lotdevcostinc~e lot development cost increase (last 10 years)
52 sflotdevcosti~e single family lot development cost increase (last 10 years)
53 time_sfu review time for single family units (months)
54 time_mfu review time for multi family units (months)
55 timechg_sfu change in review/appr time for sf projects over decade, 0=none, 1=longer, 2=much
56 timechg_mfu change in review/appr time for mf projects over decade, 0=none, 1=longer, 2=much
57 time1_l50sfu permit lag for rezoning, <50 sf units, mths-midpoint
58 time1_m50sfu permit lag for rezoning, >50 sf units, mths-midpoint
59 time1_mfu permit lag for rezoning, mf project, mths-midpoint
60 time2_l50sfu permit lag for subdivision appr (norezoning), <50 sf units, mths-midpoint
61 time2_m50sfu permit lag for subdivision appr (norezoning), >50 sf units, mths-midpoint
62 time2_mfu permit lag for subdivision appr (norezoning), mf project, mths-midpoint
63 submitted # applications for zoning changes submitted (last 12 months)
64 approved # applications for zoning changes approved (last 12 months)
65 execrating State Legislative Profile (Foster and Summers)
66 judicialrating State Judicial Profile (Foster and Summers)
67 town_meet Town Meeting for of Government
68 zonvote Town Meeting Aproves Zoning Changes
69 zonvote_super Town Meeting Aproves Zoning Changes by a Super-Majority
70 totinitiatives Total number of initiatives from 1996-2005
71 LPPI Local Political Pressure Index
72 SPII State Political Involvement Index
73 SCII State Court Involvement Index
74 LZAI Local Zoning Approval Index
75 LPAI Local Project Approval Index
76 LAI Local Assembly Index
77 DRI Density Restrictions Index
78 OSI Open Space Index
79 EI Exactions Index
80 SRI Supply Restrictions Index
81 ADI Approval Delay Index
82 WRLURI Wharton Residential Land Use Regulation Index
Table 3. Average Wharton Residential Land Use Regulation Index Values by State.
Table 3. Average Wharton Residential Land Use Regulation Index Values by State.
State Wharton Index Number of Observations
1. Hawaii 2.32 1
2. Rhode Island 1.58 17
3. Massachusetts 1.56 79
4. New Hampshire 1.36 32
5. New Jersey 0.88 104
6. Maryland 0.79 18
7. Washington 0.74 49
8. Maine 0.68 44
9. California 0.59 182
10. Arizona 0.58 40
11. Colorado 0.48 48
12. Delaware 0.48 5
13. Connecticut 0.38 65
14. Pennsylvania 0.37 182
15. Florida 0.37 97
16. Vermont 0.35 24
17. Minnesota 0.08 80
18. Oregon 0.08 42
19. Wisconsin 0.07 93
20. Michigan 0.02 111
21. New York -0.01 93
22. Utah -0.07 41
23. New Mexico -0.11 16
24. Illinois -0.19 139
25. Virginia -0.19 35
26. Georgia -0.21 56
27. North Carolina -0.35 64
28. Montana -0.36 6
29. Ohio -0.36 135
30. Texas -0.45 165
31. Nevada -0.45 7
32. Wyoming -0.45 7
33. North Dakota -0.54 8
34. Kentucky -0.57 28
35. Idaho -0.63 19
36. Tennessee -0.68 41
37. Nebraska -0.68 22
38. Oklahoma -0.7 36
39. South Carolina -0.76 30
40. Mississippi -0.82 21
41. Arkansas -0.86 23
42. West Virginia -0.9 15
43. Alabama -0.94 37
44. Iowa -0.99 59
45. Indiana -1.01 47
46. Missouri -1.03 67
47. South Dakota -1.04 11
48. Louisiana -1.06 19
49. Alaska -1.07 7
50. Kansas -1.13 46
Table 4. Wharton Residential Land Use Regulation Index Averages For Major Metropolitan Areas.
Table 4. Wharton Residential Land Use Regulation Index Averages For Major Metropolitan Areas.
Metropolitan Area Wharton Index Number of Observations
1 Providence-Fall River-Warwick 1.79 16
2 Boston 1.54 41
3 Monmouth-Ocean 1.21 15
4 Philadelphia 1.03 55
5 Seattle-Bellevue-Everett 1.01 21
6 San Francisco 0.9 13
7 Denver 0.85 13
8 Nassau-Suffolk 0.8 14
9 Bergen-Passaic 0.71 21
10 Fort Lauderdale 0.7 16
11 Phoenix-Mesa 0.7 18
12 New York 0.63 19
13 Riverside-San Bernardino 0.61 20
14 Newark 0.6 25
15 Springfield 0.58 13
16 Harrisburg-Lebanon-Carlisle 0.55 15
17 Oakland 0.52 12
18 Los Angeles-Long Beach 0.51 32
19 Hartford 0.5 28
20 San Diego 0.48 11
21 Orange County 0.39 14
22 Minneapolis-St 0.34 48
23 Washington DC 0.33 12
24 Portland-Vancouver 0.29 20
25 Milwaukee 0.25 21
26 Akron 0.15 11
27 Detroit 0.12 46
28 Allentown-Bethlehem-Easton 0.1 14
29 Chicago 0.06 95
30 Pittsburgh 0.06 44
31 Atlanta 0.04 26
32 Scranton-Wilkes-Barre-Hazelton 0.03 11
33 Salt Lake City-Ogden -0.1 19
34 Grand Rapids-Muskegon-Holland -0.15 16
35 Cleveland-Lorain-Elyria -0.16 31
36 San Antonio -0.17 12
37 Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater -0.17 12
38 Houston -0.19 13
39 San Antonio -0.24 12
40 Fort Worth-Arlington -0.27 15
41 Dallas -0.35 31
42 Oklahoma City -0.41 12
43 Dayton-Springfield -0.5 17
44 Cincinnati OH-KY-IN -0.56 27
45 St. Louis MO-IL -0.72 27
46 Indianapolis IN -0.76 12
47 Kansas City MO-KS -0.8 29
figure-2
Figure 2. Simple Correlations between Housing Prices and Explanatory Variables.
Figure 2. Simple Correlations between Housing Prices and Explanatory Variables.
figure-2
Table 5. Regression Analysis Results.
Table 5. Regression Analysis Results.
Dependent Variable: Real Median Owner Occupied Housing Price Growth, 1989-2007
(1) (2) (3)
Median Real Income Growth 0.549(4.33)*** 0.455(3.62)*** 0.489(4.00)***
Population Growth 0.172(3.74)*** 0.166(3.65)*** 0.149(3.45)***
Density 6.66E-07(3.72)*** 6.19E-07(3.52)*** 4.81E-07(2.73)***
Wharton Land Use Index 0.004(3.95)***
Permit Approval Delays 0.00037(1.6)*
Statewide Regulations 0.005(3.85)***
Courts 0.004(2.98)***
State Involvement in Local Land use and Growth Management 0.002(2.54)**
Constant 0.019(12.48)*** 0.019(12.34)*** -0.007(1.62)
Observations 253 246 246
Adj. R-squared 0.21 0.25 0.33
Root MSE 0.0132 0.01288 0.01217
Table 6. Sources of Real Housing Price Increase in Washington State.
Table 6. Sources of Real Housing Price Increase in Washington State.
Seattle Tacoma Vancouver Everett Kent
Housing Price in 20061 $447,800 $228,300 $233,600 $258,000 $281,600
Real Housing Price Change 1989-06 102% 114% 137% 62% 62%
Increase In Housing Prices Due to:
I) Common Factors Across Cities6 -$36,472 -$18,099 -$17,651 -$23,322 -$25,474
II) Income & Population Growth $35,075 $8,382 $49,185 $7,343 $24,068
III) Population Density $17,271 $5,099 $4,609 $4,968 $5,810
IV) Land Use Restrictions/Regulations $203,525 $83,265 $73,086 $113,477 $124,614
IVa) Statewide Land Use Restrictions Imposed by Executive & Legislature2 $79,106 $39,256 $38,284 $50,584 $55,253
IVb) Municipal Land Use Restrictions Upheld by Courts3 $43,796 $21,733 $21,195 2800491% $30,589
IVc) Statewide Growth Management and Residential Building Restrictions4 $50,274 $19,958 $9,732 $25,718 $21,068
IVd) Approval Delay5 $30,350 $2,317 $3,874 $9,170 $17,704
Regulation % of 2006 Housing Price 45% 36% 31% 44% 44%